Financing New Information Access Paradigms, or Why Academic Information Managers Need Cost Models Copyright 1992 CAUSE From _CAUSE/EFFECT_ Volume 15, Number 2, Summer 1992. Permission to copy or disseminate all or part of this material is granted provided that the copies are not made or distributed for commercial advantage, the CAUSE copyright and its date appear,and notice is given that copying is by permission of CAUSE, the association for managing and using information resources in higher education. To disseminate otherwise, or to republish, requires written permission.For further information, contact CAUSE, 4840 Pearl East Circle, Suite 302E, Boulder, CO 80301, 303-449-4430, e-mail info@CAUSE.colorado.edu FINANCING NEW INFORMATION ACCESS PARADIGMS, OR WHY ACADEMIC INFORMATION MANAGERS NEED COST MODELS by Richard N. Katz ************************************************************************ Richard N. Katz is Special Assistant to the Associate Vice President- Information Systems and Administrative Services of the University of California (UC), Office of the President. His responsibilities include planning for administrative and academic computing and developing administrative strategies for new UC campuses. This article is based on an address given by the author at a meeting of the Task Force of the Coalition for Networked Information (CNI) on November 21, 1991, in Washington, D.C. ************************************************************************ ABSTRACT: A fundamental shift in the way information is produced, processed, stored, and distributed has brought academic information management to a crossroads. Passage will require strategies that must include development of economic models. In March 1990, David Roselle, president of the University of Delaware, suggested that "making full and effective use of emerging telecommunications networks requires a new partnership among libraries, computer and technology experts, and concerned constituencies." With this suggestion, Roselle announced the formation of the Coalition for Networked Information (CNI) by CAUSE, EDUCOM and the Association of Research Libraries. With the objective of "advancing scholarship and intellectual productivity," the CNI is having a significant impact on higher education's planning for academic support services in spite of its short existence. As one of CNI's founders, and because it recognizes many administrative implications of emerging capabilities such as the NREN (National Research and Education Network), imaging, multimedia, and other new technologies, CAUSE believes that it is important that its members understand the issues and directions under consideration, debate, and development by the CNI. One premise of the CNI and of much planning for academic support services at American colleges and universities is that "the real value of the network [NREN] will result from information resources and services made available to a broad user community." To promote an understanding of the new opportunities posed by the NREN and to prepare the ground for an expected paradigm shift both in the delivery of information services and in scholarly communication, the CNI is engaged in a wide range of planning activities and technological ventures and demonstration projects. Among these endeavors is an ongoing effort to foster dialogue and studies on the economics of information delivery. This effort is designed to inform librarians, publishers, and technologists of the challenges, opportunities, risks, and benefits associated with investments in the infrastructure that will be necessary to support new information access paradigms. While many readers of CAUSE/EFFECT may not have formal responsibilities associated with the discussion that follows, the issues facing the academic information manager and the administrative information manager are the same. Over a reasonably short time horizon, administrative information managers, like their academic counterparts, will be expected to provide easy and seamless access to institutional and external data to their constituents. Even the reasons for this requirement will be the same--the need to improve the productivity of the academy. In the future, administrative employees at all levels will be empowered to resolve a variety of institutional problems. The ability to solve these problems will be determined to a large extent by how well the campus information technology providers organize their environments to provide employees with easy access to a wide range of information, in a variety of media. The CNI effort to foster dialogue and studies on the economics of information delivery resulted in the organization of a conference in March 1991. The so-called "Monterey conference" brought scholars, technologists, librarians, and publishers together in an attempt to address an emerging crisis in serials pricing. Over the past decade, few areas of academic activity have seen their costs rise as quickly as has the academic journal acquisition function. The twin pressures of declining budgets and escalating journal prices have led many college and university libraries to curtail sharply their purchases. Attendees of the CNI's Monterey conference exchanged views on the underlying causes of this price escalation and identified the need to develop economic models of the costs of accessing and distributing scholarly information on paper, image, character text, or other media. Academic information management at a crossroads One of the messages of the Monterey conference was that academic information management is at a crossroads: for the first time in recorded history, academic information managers are in a position to bring the information mountain to Mohammed. The history of the library profession--tracing to the great library of stone tablets in Alexandria --has been predicated on the very sensible premise that it is easier and more cost effective to collect mankind's writings in great repositories and to cause the users of these writings to gather at the well, so to speak, than it would be to manufacture and distribute sufficient numbers of copies to satisfy users' demands. Libraries as stores of recorded knowledge served at least four significant economic goals. First, they reduced manufacturing costs. In earliest times, one can imagine the cost of creating stone tablets to be quite high. Second, libraries, through centralization, achieved economies of scale in the processing of recorded knowledge. Third, the library-storehouse introduced scale economies in the storage of information. Finally, the storehouse concept reduced institutional distribution costs by rationing access to the collections and by passing most of these costs along to the library patron. The library-as- storehouse concept has served mankind effectively for millennia. However, it is important to remember that this concept was devised and refined due largely to the idiosyncracies of the prevailing writing technology of the day--be it tablet, scroll, sheepskin, papyrus, or book. A second impression left from the Monterey conference was that there exist significant misunderstandings about basic economic concepts such as cost, price, and value, and that these misunderstandings stem, more than anything, from the cultural and linguistic traditions and perspectives of librarians, publishers, technologists, and scholars. The threshold issue for all parties is the matter of the crossroads. We are in the midst of a major shift in the climate in higher education. This change of climate is being manifested along the economic, political, and technological dimensions. Those of us with responsibility for managing higher education's information or technology resources sense a fundamental shift in the means by which information is produced, processed, stored, and distributed. The pace of technological change is accelerating and we should remind ourselves that it was only thirty years ago that the first patent was issued for the integrated circuit and that the IBM PC was only introduced ten short years ago. Less than one year ago, the U.S. Court of Appeals gave the seven regional Bell Operating Companies permission to offer electronic information services over their networks. Finally, as we await the emergence of the NREN, we have witnessed the 700-factor increase in data network bandwidth since 1987. Estimates of the user population on these networks range anywhere from 2 million to 20 million people. While these developments mean many things to many people, to economists and to business people they mean no less than the creation of a mass market for electronic information. As critical mass is achieved we can expect the suppliers to these markets to be bigger in economic size and influence. For these reasons, the consumers of information will need strategies. What will emergefrom the crucible described are new paradigms for delivery of information. It will be important for us to recall that new paradigms of this kind are not, after all, new. Over the past 150 years we have witnessed new ways of delivering verbal messages (the telephone), goods (railroads, trucks), people (cars, airplanes), and images (television, facsimile). Why is it so hard to anticipate new ways of delivering academic information? In fact, we have more than once (stone tablets, papyrus, books, CDs) changed fundamentally the way in which recorded information is created, processed, stored, and communicated. What I am alluding to here is the concept of life cycles. Life scientists, technologists, business planners, and others work closely with the concept of life cycles to help them understand the development of insects, technologies, products, and markets. Life cycles are composed of four stages which can be described as gestation, growth, maturity, and aging. As prevailing technologies mature and age, the investment required to achieve a defined result will increase. The decreasing return on investment often inspires inventors to find a better way, resulting in the emergence of competitive products, services, or technologies with differing cost structures, different attributes, and different appeal to consumers. The life cycle concept is important because the emergence of new products and technologies can result in tremendous economic adjustment. Economic adjustment is the term economists euphemistically use to describe a process of upheaval that often accompanies technological change. In this upheaval, markets and economic relationships can be altered fundamentally. In short, there are winners and losers. I submit to you that we are at such crossroads now; that those of us who choose to stay on the existing life cycle curve that is focused on paper-based access to information will witness a decreasing return on investments. Conversely, those of us who invest in the infrastructure to support new electronic delivery paradigms may be able to meet the increasing needs of our constituents more effectively. Why are we at a crossroads? It is no longer news that higher education in the U.S. faces a dramatically new economic climate. In 1990-91, thirty states made mid- year cuts in higher education budgets averaging 3.9 percent. Last year, the increase in tax support to higher education dropped to its lowest level in thirty years. At the same time, colleges and universities failed to keep the rise in costs to a level at or below the consumer price index. Over the decade of the 1990s state budgets are forecast to be in deficit, federal funding of research is likely to come under new pressure, and the supply of eligible students will be flat or negative in all but three or four states. Decreasing research funding and new caps on indirect cost rates may also slow the flow of funds into higher education. At the same time, governments, corporations, and parents are demanding increasing accountability from colleges and universities as a condition of their support. Any analysis of the demographics will reveal a swelling in the ranks of those in our primary and secondary schools. Our politicians, in an era of resource constraints and a boom of school age children, will find it easy to defer support of higher education in favor of the more politically compelling needs of grades K-12. Another key trend will be the increased focus on the undergraduate instructional element of the university mission. This shift in focus recognizes the possible diminution of federal support for research as well as increased pressure from parents and students. For many institutions, the changing economic and political climate will mean nothing less than a struggle for survival through the 1990s. To face such struggles, colleges and universities are more than ever setting academic strategies to focus their programs and resources to attract students and faculty. Finally, in many quarters substantial calls to revise the reward systems for faculty are being heard. In Monterey, much of the problem in serials pricing was ascribed to the "publish or perish" system of faculty evaluation and the tendency of such research incentives to foster the proliferation of publications without commensurate demands for quality. The recent moves at Harvard and Stanford to base tenure and promotion decisions, in part, on the top six publications may have a dramatic impact on both academic publishing and information management. Also bringing us to the crossroads is the new technical climate in higher education that we, in part, are trying to usher in. Elements of this environment to watch include the NREN, cooperative processing, multimedia, HDTV, and cellular communications. A final reason for emphasizing the crossroads metaphor is the change in the external environment. In the course of virtually every industry life cycle is a period of vertical integration and consolidation. As a mass market for the delivery of networked information matures, we will see an increase in this integration and consolidation. Perhaps the most recent example can be drawn from the motion picture and broadcast television industries which, in less than ten years, have witnessed the demise of the consent decrees and financial syndication rules that prevented widespread vertical integration. Owing largely to technological developments and to competitive pressures to reach global markets, this industry has witnessed rapid deregulation and integration of programming producers, distributors, and exhibitors. This level of consolidation has been occurring in the publishing industry and will continue to do so, particularly as the telecommunications companies organize to offer information services through networks. In sum, we face a crossroads in which budgets are shrinking, supplier power is increasing, and a competitive market for networked information is maturing. So what does this mean to us? What it means is nothing less than what was described earlier as economic adjustment. Virtually every economic relationship that has characterized academic information management since the commercialization of the book is in a process of fundamental change. I pose to you a number of potential changes to these existing economic relationships in the form of a series of propositions. First, and potentially most speculative, the supply of published scholarly information may fall. Such a decrease in the supply of publications may stem from changes to the faculty evaluation process and research support levels discussed earlier and may be reinforced by an increase in the use of data communications networks as vehicles for the more informal scholarly exchange of ideas and research findings. Second, a decreasing supply of published information is likely to raise the value of information published. New information delivery channels, with new cost structures, will facilitate a fundamental re- thinking of what scholars publish and how they publish. While a formal publication process will always form an element of the scholarly communication and quality control process, we can no longer make assumptions about the size and nature of that communication niche that includes formal peer review and the imprimatur of the academic publishing apparatus. Third, the cost structures of academic publishing and information management will likely change. Printing, computing, and networking are capital-intensive activities that require large investments in fixed costs. If, for example, the sale of electronic books and serials cannibalizes the sales of the same books and serials in print, the unit costs of printed publications will rise. These changing costs will have differential impacts on colleges and universities. In essence, colleges and universities that have chosen to invest in network infrastructures may witness falling unit or total costs, while those that have not may experience rising costs. The arena in which these potential impacts will be played out is the arena of pricing. Our crystal balls can perhaps be clearest where it comes to support costs. The introduction of online bibliographic databases, CDs, and other electronic library tools and sources has demonstrably failed to reduce library support costs. I can see no trend, short of a wholesale circumvention of the library as an information intermediary, that is likely to lower these support costs. Another powerful change is what I refer to as the increasing control on fair use. The nearly $2 million settlement of the recent case against Kinko's Copy Centers bears witness to the stakes along this front. In the era preceding the proliferation of copiers, fair use of published information was regulated by the time and expense of alternate modes of copying. Since the copier's introduction we have witnessed the degradation of publishers' and authors' ability to police the financial recovery of their copyrights. Networked information delivery paradigms will increase the efficiency by which we account for use and will thereby increase returns to copyright holders and costs to users. There will also be a probable proliferation of information outlets. Publishers, utilities, regional coalitions, and collectives, in this context, may compete to deliver information faster, cheaper, and more conveniently to our students and faculty. This possibility, too, may have dramatic impacts on our investment strategies. Finally, as we move towards the promise of networked information we are likely to see a continued rise in the service expectations of our constituents. While the natural self-rationing qualities of the books have been understood and accepted by scholars for millennia, these qualities will be rejected by present and future generations of network babies raised in an era of immediate gratification of information needs. Where in the past books, then computers, and then networks have been the scarce good, now faculty time is in the shortest supply. The growth of document delivery services and the proliferation of fax machines bear witness to this emerging focus on speed of delivery. Importantly, we are also learning that time is money and that many will pay to receive information quickly. The metaphor I'll use here is again the motion picture industry. Today, one can pay $8.00 to see a first run movie, pay $3.00 to see the same movie on video cassette or on pay-per-view, pay 30 cents a day to see the same movie via cable, or pay nothing to view that very same movie on broadcast TV. The value of the information to the end consumer, and therefore the price he or she is willing to pay, is mediated by time. I believe that academic publishers and information managers will be able to offer this same range of services to students and scholars and to price accordingly. Strategy setting is key One major implication of the trends described is the unprecedented need for academic information management professionals to set a strategy now--one that assumes the existence of a new information storage and delivery infrastructure. Elements of this strategy include: * doing more, with less * investing in infrastructure * funding innovation * forging alliances * developing economic models. As just stated, in an era of resource constraints coupled with a likelihood of supplier consolidation, we will have to do more with less. This is why organizations such as CNI are, in my opinion, indispensable. As we information managers set institutional strategies, we must recognize that our suppliers are setting theirs. Publishers, recall, operate in the same macroeconomic and technical context as their customers and are positioning themselves to survive or thrive in the coming economic adjustment. As I see it, our attention must turn to ways in which both the publishers and the managers of academic information prosper under the emerging technological context. We can do this by examining the underlying economics of our respective areas of interest. The central objective of our professions should not be to reduce serial or monograph prices; rather it should be to organize and deploy the emerging network infrastructure to lower our institutions' total information life cycle costs without jeopardizing publishers' rights to fair return on investment. I believe that this objective can be met. To accomplish this, publishers must explore ways of reducing costs or expanding their franchise. Networked information delivery as an element of overall corporate strategy can accomplish this. For example, just-in-time publishing, a model in which textbooks are printed on demand and updated quickly, has reduced the cost of inventory for publishers dramatically. This kind of use of information technology alone has the potential to revolutionize the economics of publishing by eliminating one major investment risk associated with the process. Similarly, institutional strategies that incorporate networked information will potentially reduce information management life cycle costs by eliminating those curatorial costs that are associated with the medium of paper. Developing a new economic model for libraries What I think we need is a robust model of library costs that is based on a highly generalized architecture of information. As a point of departure, this architecture, and its associated costs, should describe the current library. One such architecture is described by Davis and Davidson in their recent book, 2020 Vision. The Davis-Davidson model greatly simplifies the function of libraries and other information intermediaries by identifying a very limited number of forms and functions to be performed. Information, these authors claim, occurs in only four basic forms: data, sound, image, and text. Information management, in this framework, consists of four basic functions to be performed on information in these forms. These functions are generation, processing, storage, and transmission. While in many contexts this architectural model simplifies excessively the complex world of academic libraries, I am comfortable with the suggestion that all the information management activities we engage in are variations on these core functions. A simple architectural model will help us develop a simplified economic model that describes the flow of information and physical library materials through the modern university research library. I refer to such a model as "the base case" because, if endorsed, such a model can then be used to evaluate the costs and investment requirements of switching to alternate cases. I propose that, as we begin to describe the base case, we distinguish between the costs and flows of information and those of physical "things." It is essential at this time to reinforce a point alluded to earlier, that is, that books, serials, and government publications are not information; rather, they are specific forms of packaging and organizing of information that have been optimized for efficiency in generation, processing, storage, and transmission. Methodologically, we will need to devise standard metrics for costing academic information management activities, in effect creating a set of generally accepted accounting practices, or GAAP, for libraries. We need to come to agreement on units of analysis for costing purposes. My sense here is that the cost of managing serials is sufficiently different from that of monographs to suggest a differential costing analysis by major library product line. A robust cost model should be comprehensive. Within the proposed architectural framework, all library costs associated with acquiring, processing, storing, and circulating information should be allocated. Necessarily, such allocations will not be neat and clean due to our attempt to simplify grossly a complex enterprise. While the misallocation of library costs to any one of our four functional categories may be cause for internal or political concern, it should not compromise the model. What will be critical to the development of the base case will be the differentiation of activities and costs on the basis of whether or not those activities and costs relate to managing information or to managing things. By identifying and differentiating media-specific costs from those that are a function of information content management, we will create models that can be used to study the costs of switching to other delivery paradigms. In the spirit of keeping things simple, I'd like to propose that for now we set aside the issues of pricing. From the viewpoint of our architectural model and from that of the institution, the cost we pay for generating information is equal to the price we pay for that information. Regarding processing, there are numerous complex processes that libraries, publishers, utilities, and others perform to acquire information and to establish intellectual and physical control of acquired information. Some of these processes and their costs are what I call medium-specific, such as the physical receiving and shelving of books and the creation of control tools such as shelf lists. Other activities and costs are invested to achieve a level of institutional awareness of the contents of the institutional repository and are medium-independent. I am inclined to believe that the costs of abstracting, for example, will remain constant for any particular journal whether that journal is delivered by UPS or over the NREN. Intuitively, I suspect the area of storage is where we are likely to get our biggest return on investment in new information delivery paradigms. A comprehensive life cycle cost model of the modern academic library must include an amortization of the facility construction costs, as well as a recognition of maintenance, utility, and other facility costs prorated to the book or journal level. I believe that most of the storage costs of the current academic research library are tied very closely to our predominant reliance on paper. It is my hope that analysis of this kind will reveal these costs to be among the highest in our existing delivery framework. Such a finding will give us a persuasive and perhaps compelling argument for investing in networked information delivery systems in the spirit of doing more, for less. Lastly, we will need to assess the costs of circulating our holdings among our customers. In this context, I use the term circulation broadly to include all of these activities engaged in by libraries that put requested information into the hands of library patrons. I've listed here only a few such activities and cost centers, and I offer a final activity in the spirit of a "trial balloon." That one is, of course, customer time. If you recall, I argued earlier that libraries achieve certain economies by passing many of the costs of circulating information on to the customer. As the mission of CNI states, we are now concerned more than ever with increasing scholarly productivity. If this is to be more than a hollow commitment to productivity, I close by suggesting that we consider factoring into our economic analysis the opportunity cost of faculty time. Conclusion Academic information managers, campus technology managers, and networked service providers may be positioned to deliver on a promise of doing more, with less. In addition to making the innovations and investments that the networked information paradigm will require, we in higher education administration must begin to assess, model, and communicate our library costs from the point of view of information access, as well as information acquisition. Only when we have a holistic, and user-oriented, model of the base case costs will we be able to make meaningful comparisons to, and trade-offs among, new networked information delivery paradigms. Such analysis and future comparisons will help inform our decisions about how to invest and, where necessary, how to cut. The challenges facing higher education in the 1990s are daunting. More than ever, those information and information technology managers among us are in a position to help our institutions weather the storm, while improving services to faculty and students. While perhaps unexciting, developing a comprehensive model of the base case costs of delivering books and serials to faculty and students will go far in enabling the next campus academic information delivery paradigm. ======================================================================== For further reading: Davis, Stanley M., and William H. Davidson. 2020 Vision: Transform Your Business Today to Succeed in Tomorrow's Economy. New York: Simon & Schuster, 1991. ========================================================================